Jumat, 30 Juli 2010

Want to be a pro bono economic expert? In re Apple & ATTM Antitrust Litig.

0 komentar
When Apple introduced its iPhone into a smartphone market where it had 0% market share, it cut a deal with AT&T Mobility to make it the exclusive provider of cell phone service.  In exchange, ATTM subsidized the price of every iPhone by $450, thus ensuring that more consumers would be able to purchase iPhones, and introducing additional competition into the smartphone market. 

Nonetheless, trial lawyers sued, bringing a class action alleging that this basic business arrangement violated the antitrust laws because it threatened to monopolize the previously non-existent market for "iPhone telephone service." 

This is ludicrous on its face.  The smartphone market is more competitive than ever: in addition to the longstanding Blackberry, there's new entrants Droid and HTC Evo (and vis-a-vis the latter, see this NSFW, but very funny, video).  Without the phone carrier subsidization, many iPhone owners (including me) would be unable to afford an iPhone, and are clearly better off because of the exclusivity deal.  Nonetheless, the Northern District of California has certified a class action over the practice—and not just any class, but a Rule 23(b)(2) mandatory class, meaning that every iPhone owner with an AT&T Mobility two-year contract is now involuntarily represented by attorneys that apparently care more about the possibility of extortionate settlement profit than the clients they purportedly represent. 

The Center for Class Action Fairness is in talks with a number of iPhone owners who are concerned about being represented by class counsel who don't have their best interest at heart, and considering filing papers moving to intervene and decertify the class.  But economic experts willing to go on the record to refute quack antitrust analysis are not cheap; before we blow a good chunk of our annual budget on one, we're curious if there's anyone out there willing to work for a discount rate or, better yet, pro bono.  (In the alternative, if there's another public-interest law firm out there who'd like to take the lead role on this, I am happy to serve pro bono as both the client class member iPhone owner and as the expert witness, as well as assist on the legal side.  Unfortunately, legal rules prohibit me from serving as both lead attorney and as a witness.)

Kamis, 29 Juli 2010

Dewey v. Volkswagen, Water Ingress Settlement fairness hearing

0 komentar
A tiny percentage of Volkswagen and Audi sunroofs will leak into the vehicle unless care is taken to keep the plenum clear of debris; a class action was brought over this.  Let's assume for the moment that plaintiffs are correct that this is something that Volkswagen is liable for, and that there are contractual remedies for VW not foolproofing the cars against this problem.  What's remarkable is how the parties settled the case in such a way so that wildly inefficient remedies would maximize attorneys' fees at the expense of the class.  The settlement is structured as follows:
  1. A million class members will get nothing but a letter telling them to check the plenum when they go for their 40,000-mile service.
  2. VW will perform an expensive preventative service action on some, but not all, VWs that might suffer this problem.
  3. An $8 million settlement fund is set up to pay damages for some, but not all, VWs that have suffered damage
The economic expert for the plaintiff made some remarkable calculations.  For example, he valued the letter at over $29 million.  After all, if you get a letter informing you of a potential benefit, that letter is worth just as much as the benefit itself—never mind that Volkswagen dealers charge $400 to $800 for 40,000-mile service, and can easily choose to raise the price $30 to account for the extra labor in performing the extra task during the maintenance service.  So if Apple ever settles a class action by sending you a letter telling you you can buy a $700 iPad for $700, that is, according to the expert, indistinguishable from Apple writing each consumer a check for $700.

Let's look at #2 for a second.  According to the plaintiff's own expert, VW will spend $55 million on that service action.  According to the same expert, if VW does not perform the maintenance, those vehicles will suffer $24 million in damage.  (The expert then remarkably triple-counts this as a benefit to the class: the $24 million in damage avoided, plus $55 million in VW expenses for the service action, plus another $24 million for the avoided diminution of value of the vehicle that would have occurred if the vehicles suffered damage and then weren't repaired.  Thus, according to the expert, this component of the settlement is worth over $103 million.)  Spending $55 million to avoid $24 million in damage is the very definition of economic inefficiency. 

But consumers lose out.  Some of the class members who are getting nothing but a letter—including one of my clients—have suffered actual damage from sunroof leakage.  They're not getting paid under this settlement and are being forced to release their claims, which are no less meritorious than the claims that are getting paid.

The only possible reason for plaintiffs' attorneys to insist upon this convoluted remedy is to increase attorneys' fees.  By making Volkswagen engage in wasteful spending, they pump up the alleged value of the settlement and then argue that they're entitled to over $23 million in attorneys' fees and costs, to be paid separately by Volkswagen.

It would have been very easy to structure a settlement so that Volkswagen created a $48 million fund to cover repairs to every vehicle that suffered water damage from a sunroof leak.  Every VW owner who had the problem in the past or in the future would be able to collect; Volkswagen would be out of pocket $48 million instead of $70-$90 million; the attorneys could have made a plausible claim for $10 million in attorneys' fees and costs from the fund, which would still be close to twice an exaggerated lodestar.  Instead, the parties negotiated a settlement that made everyone—consumers and Volkswagen—worse off.  Well, everyone except the attorneys, if Judge Patty Shwartz buys the quack economic testimony and awards the full fee request.

Under Rule 23(e), a judge is not to approve a settlement unless it is "fair, adequate, and reasonable."  It is hard to see how this settlement is fair or reasonable; and it demonstrates the failure of legal ethics that the class attorneys could structure this settlement and make that fee request without fear of sanction, even as they put their own interests ahead of their clients.

The four-hour fairness hearing, consisting mostly of the economic expert rationalizing his calculation and the attorneys arguing over fees, was last Monday in a Newark federal courtroom.  I look forward to seeing how the judge will rule.

Rabu, 21 Juli 2010

Ninth Circuit appeal over cy pres: Nachshin v. AOL

0 komentar
Tuesday, the Center filed its opening brief appealing the approval of a class action settlement against AOL.  We focused our appeal on the problematic cy pres award in that case:
This appeal presents a straightforward application of the Ninth Circuit precedent Six Mexican Workers v. Arizona Citrus Growers, 904 F.2d 1301 (9th Cir. 1990)—a precedent that the district court entirely failed to apply. For a cy pres award to a third party to be permissible it must actually be “cy pres”—as near as possible to actual class recovery. Id. at 1308. Here, there was a nationwide class of tens of millions of AOL members allegedly victimized by AOL practices, but the vast majority of the cy pres distribution went to local charities in the Los Angeles and Oklahoma areas; all of the cy pres was entirely unrelated to the class and unrelated to the claims of the case.
The potential of cy pres to create conflicts of interest and ethical dilemmas for the judiciary have garnered increasing attention in recent years. See, e.g., Adam Liptak, Doling Out Other People’s Money, N.Y. TIMES (Nov. 26, 2007) (available at http://www.nytimes.com/2007/11/26/washington/26bar.html); Martin H. Redish, et al., Cy Pres Relief and the Pathologies of the Modern Class Action: A Normative and Empirical Analysis, 62 FLA. L. REV. __ (forthcoming 2010) (available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1485047); Sam Yospe, Cy Pres Distributions in Class Action Settlements, 2009 COLUMBIA BUS. L. REV. 1014 (available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1492105); Amanda Bronstad, Cy pres awards under scrutiny, NAT’L L. J. (Aug. 11, 2008) (available at http://is.gd/dyFk0-). If courts are going to countenance cy pres distributions in class actions settlements at all, such distributions must be strictly tethered to the standard of class benefit, lest cy pres become a slush fund for plaintiffs, defendants, attorneys, and judges that creates the appearance of impropriety—or worse, actual impropriety.
The problems of potential conflicts of interest are not just a hypothetical concern in the case at bar. Neither the court nor the class was informed of the conflict of interest that one of the plaintiffs was the assistant director of development for one of the cy pres recipients. And yet still another cy pres recipient was a local charity where the spouse of the district court judge sits on the board. It is not exaggerating to say that this case is a poster child for the problem of cy pres abuse: indeed, in a story on the issue, the Wall Street Journal singled out the very settlement in this case as an example. Nathan Koppel, Proposed Facebook Settlement Comes Under Fire, WALL ST. J. (Mar. 2, 2010) (available at http://is.gd/dyl7A-).
For both precedential and sound public-policy reasons, this court should reverse the approval of the proposed class action settlement as an abuse of discretion.

Senin, 19 Juli 2010

Eliminating The Long Wait Through Purchase Structured Settlements

0 komentar
Institutions that purchase structured settlements purchase future payments in exchange for a cash advance. The amount you get is a discounted amount that includes the firm’s fees. This simply means that you get your cash right away. This will be much better than waiting for your monthly allotment. People who take this option no longer have to wait for the monthly or yearly payments from these settlements. You instantly get cash at hand.
If you have won a case involving injury, medical malpractice, defective products, a family member’s wrongful death, there is sure to be a settlement well in its way. The settlements offered in these cases involve large amounts of money. However, they are set up to be paid in increments over a period of time. They can be paid in a matter of months, years, or during your entire lifetime. This assures the recipient an amount of money in the duration given.
Due to the increments paid in the months or years ordered by the court, there are advantages when it comes to tax. Furthermore, you are assured a steady income for the future. By receiving the large sum all at once, there is a large chance that there will be nothing left in the future. This is best seen in people who need to pay for medical expenses. They will need to pay for their health care, as well as set aside money for the coming future.
However, there are cases when there is an immediate need for the large sum of money. This is when purchase structured settlements come in handy. We can never tell what the future may bring. This includes emergencies or immediate needs. In this case, immediate cash is needed. The monthly or yearly payments will not do.
This is when you will need purchase structured settlements. The reasons vary. You may need it for college, you may need it to purchase a house, or you may need it for situations you never planned for. This is when you will need all the money involved in the settlement.
When making use of this option, you do not get the entire amount. However, you do get ready cash at hand. The company charges a fee ranging from 10% to 30% of the entire amount. The advantage here is that you do not get insignificant monthly or yearly payments. You get a much larger amount through purchase structured settlements. This gives you more options.
You can opt to sell the entire settlement amount, or you can opt to sell just a portion of it. For whatever option you plan to take, you are assured ready cash for whatever need you might have. In today’s unsteady financial crisis, there are a lot of people who take this option.
When a need presents itself, you no longer have to worry about not being prepared. There are options you can take to cash in on your settlement. This way, you are always prepared. Through purchase structured settlements, you eliminate the long wait.

Selasa, 13 Juli 2010

A post for Fed Jur buffs only

0 komentar
Parties in a class action agree to submit to the jurisdiction of an Article I magistrate under 28 U.S.C. § 636(c).  Then they settle the case.  Objectors show up, but have not consented to have the case heard by a magistrate.  Does the magistrate still have jurisdiction or does an Article III judge have to weigh in? 

Section 636(c) requires consent by "parties."  Are unnamed class members parties under § 636(c)?  One can't just give the answer of a blanket "no"; the statute and federal rules are silent, and Devlin v. Scardelletti, 536 U.S. 1 (2002), says that class members are sometimes "parties," and sometimes not. 

The problem, of course, is the possibility of heads-I-win/tails-you-lose gamesmanship, with an objector throwing a wrench into the proceedings by protesting after the fact that the court didn't have jurisdiction.  See, e.g., Mark I, Inc. v. Gruber, 38 F.3d 369, 370 (7th Cir. 1994) (vacating final decision of magistrate made after two years of litigation on jurisdictional grounds). To a certain extent, the Mark I problem has been eliminated by Roell v. Withrow, 538 U.S. 580, 590 (2003), which allows a court to infer consent by acquiescence. More worrying is the possibility that an objector in good faith appeals a magistrate's ruling to an appellate court, only to learn that the appellate court does not have jurisdiction and she missed the deadline for appealing to the district court.

It's an interesting academic question, but litigants don't like the uncertainty of academic questions.  It's come up in an objection CCAF made, and we've asked the court for clarification—since no one else seems to have even thought of the issue.

Well, perhaps someone did think of it.  A so-called professional objector has the incentive to sandbag, since the business model is to lose at the district court level and then threaten a colorable appeal that would delay the class counsel payday unless paid off; a defendant is likely indifferent to delay.  What astonishes me most, however, is that plaintiffs' attorneys asking the court for $2900/hour, and presumably concerned about "professional objectors" coming in and holding up the settlement and their attorneys' fees, didn't anticipate this potentially fatal flaw.  If the attorneys who think they're worth $2900/hour are missing this basic issue-spotting that I caught, maybe I'm worth $3000/hour and even more underpaid than I thought.  (And in that case, you, loyal reader, have just benefited from $1500 worth of my time.)

Sabtu, 10 Juli 2010

Robert Booth Trust v. William Crowley, Sears Holding Corporation shareholder derivative lawsuit

0 komentar
If you're a Sears Holding Corporation (SHLD) shareholder like me, there's a pretty big chance that you got a letter in the mail informing you of a derivative shareholder settlement where the attorneys got $925,000 and the shareholders got the privilege of paying the attorneys $925,000.  The deadline for objecting was June 25.

All well and good, except that my particular notice letter arrived on June 28.  That's because, though the settlement occurred on April 28, and the court approved notice on May 11, the parties didn't bother to ask brokers to provide a list of shareholders until June 1, and then, after receiving the list, didn't bother to mail the notice to tens of thousands of shareholders until June 22 or June 23. 

I was in Chicago yesterday to object to the problematic notice.  While there I met another shareholder who didn't object to the appalling settlement because she also got her notice after the deadline.

The parties initially argued that it was alright to structure notice so that half the shareholders would receive it only after the fact, but after they gauged the judge's reaction to my argument, the parties volunteered to send new notice.  The http://www.searsholdingsderivative.com/ website has not been updated as of Saturday morning, but the new deadline will be August 20, with a new fairness hearing August 27.

The law firm involved, Vianale & Vianale, brings zero-damages lawsuits against corporations alleging technical violations of Section 8 the Clayton Act antitrust law but seeking injunctive relief, and threatens to cost the defendants millions of dollars in litigation expenses if they don't settle.  This is of no benefit to shareholders, because the law in question, when it is enforced, results in the FTC politely requesting a corporation to correct the technical violation; there has not been a government fine issued for "interlocking directorates" in my adult lifetime, and for at least several years before.  The Center will be objecting to this settlement: how can attorneys claim to represent the shareholders when rational shareholders would never agree ex ante to bring a lawsuit that is guaranteed to make them worse off, win or lose?

It generally seems that the majority of my readers are plaintiffs' law firms checking up on me, but if you happen to stumble across this post and happen to own SHLD, you might get a postcard letting you know that you have another opportunity to object.  Of course, unless you own hundreds of thousands of dollars worth of stock, it might be economically irrational to spend two 44-cent stamps to object; and if you did own that much stock, the opportunity cost of the time you spend objecting is probably pretty high, even if it's just to say "My name is X, my address and phone is Y, I own Z shares of stock, and I join in the objection of Theodore H. Frank."  But unfortunately, plaintiffs' attorneys regularly ask courts to view the rational silence of class members or shareholders as acquiescence in their extortionate theft of shareholder money.
 

class actions settlements. Copyright 2008 All Rights Reserved Revolution Two Church theme by Brian Gardner Bloganol dot com